Skip to content

Is Paper Money Constitutional?

Spread the love

14

pdfimg

Copyright Martin A. Armstrong, all right reserved March 18th, 2012

25

Please register for Special Updates

ArmstrongEconomics.COM / Princeton Economic Institute

Copyright Martin A. Armstrong All Rights Reserved 

33

Disclaimer: Futures, Options, and Currency trading all have large potential rewards, but also large potential risk. You must be aware of the risks and be willing to accept them in order to invest in these complex markets. Don’t trade with money you can t afford to lose and NEVER trade anything blindly. You must strive to understand the markets and to act upon your conviction when well researched. This is neither a solicitation nor an offer to Buy/Sell futures, options, or currencies. No representation is being made that any account will or is likely to achieve profits or losses. Indeed, events can materialize rapidly and thus past performance of any trading system or methodology is not necessarily indicative of future results particularly when you understand we are going through an economic evolution process and that includes the rise and fall of various governments globally on an economic basis.

 

CFTC Rule 4.41   Any simulated or hypothetical performance results have certain inherent limitations. While prices may appear within a given trading range, there is no guarantee that there will be enough liquidity (volume) to ensure that such trades could be actually
executed.  Hypothetical results thus can differ greatly from actual performance records, and do not represent actual trading since such trades have not actually been executed, these results may have under-or over-compensated for the impact, if any, of certain market
factors, such as lack of liquidity. Simulated or hypothetical trading programs in general are also subject to the fact that they are designed with the benefit of hindsight and back testing. Such representations in theory could be altered by Acts of God or Sovereign Debt
Defaults.

 

It should not be assumed that the methods, techniques, or indicators presented in this publication will be profitable or that they will not result in losses since this cannot be a full representation of all considerations and the evolution of economic and market development..
Past results of any individual or trading strategy published are not indicative of future returns since all things cannot be considered for
discussion purposes. In addition, the indicators, strategies, columns, articles and discussions (collectively, the  Information ) are
provided for informational and educational purposes only and should not be construed as investment advice or a solicitation for money to manage since money management is not conducted. Therefore, by no means is this publication to be construed as a solicitation of any
order to buy or sell. Accordingly, you should not rely solely on the Information in making any investment. Rather, you should use the Information only as a starting point for doing additional independent research in order to allow you to form your own opinion regarding
investments. You should always check with your licensed financial advisor and tax advisor to determine the suitability of any  such
investment.

 

Copyright 2012 Martin A. Armstrong All Rights Reserved. Protected by copyright laws of the United States and international treaties. This report may NOT be forwarded to any other party and remains the exclusive property of Martin Armstrong and is merely leased to the recipient for educational purposes. 

41

ArmstrongEconomics.COM

We have been constructing our Public Service Website with a historical archive of previous reports and essays on our economic and model research. In addition, you will find a free library of major economic works, the history of interest rates, Monetary System and much more. We will be providing our forecasting services shortly and much of our historical and political research will remain as a public service.

So please visit our site while it is being constructed. We will also be address emails and Twitter updates when new reports are posted. There will be a blog for immediate commentary when special or important market events take place 

[email protected]

25

52

Copyright Martin Armstrong All Rights Reserved April 12th, 2012

PAPER MONEY WAS DECLARED

UNCONSTITUTIONAL & SO THEY

MANIPULATED THE SUPREME COURT
TO LEGALIZE PAPER MONEY 

One of the fascinating aspects of all the controversy about paper money v hard money, has been the lack of knowledge of just how did it come about? Oh we can go back to paper money being a receipt from bullion dealers offering money storage, and we can go the American Colonial Period and point to the drastic shortage of coin that necessitated paper money issues. But those stories are fairly common knowledge. What isn t talked about even in school is the manipulation of the Supreme Court AFTER it declared that PAPER MONEY WAS UNCONSTITUTIONAL! 

The Legal Tender Cases 

The Legal Tender Cases were a series of United States Supreme Court cases in the late 19th century dealing with the constitutionality of paper money. In the 1870 case of Hepburn v. Griswold, 75 US 603 (1869) the Supreme Court had held that paper money violated the United States Constitution. The reasoning expressed in this decision is still relevant today. Of course, there is no rule of law in the United States because judges are appointed for life by political interests. Today, it is a rare judge indeed who will defend the constitution or the right of the individual over that of the government. Most are former prosecutors or judge s clerks, and there is hardly ever anyone appointed from the real people. Consequently, the constitution has lost all it’s worth and meaning.

 Fifth Amendment

No person shall be held to answer for a capital, or otherwise infamous crime, unless on a presentment or indictment of a Grand Jury, except in cases arising in the land or naval forces, or in the Militia, when in actual service in time of War or public danger; nor shall any person be subject for the same offense to be twice put in jeopardy of life or limb; nor shall be compelled in any criminal case to be a witness
against himself, nor be deprived of life, liberty, or property, without due process of law; nor shall
private property be taken for public use, without just compensation. 

The Hepburn Case primarily involved the constitutionality of the Legal Tender Act of 1862 that had been enacted during the Civil War. In Hepburn, Chief Justice Salmon P. Chase held only for a 4-3 majority of the Court that the Act was an unconstitutional violation of the Fifth Amendment. Ironically, Chief Justice Chase had played a role in formulating the Legal Tender Act of 1862, previously when he was Secretary of the Treasury. This merely demonstrates that a 6governmental person if honest, merely argues whatever will benefit the government regardless whether that is correct. Once Chase was Chief Justice, he struck down the very Act he championed.

Nevertheless, the corruption within politics is just too great for the people to ever have a fair and honest way to manage society. On the very same day that Hepburn case was announced, President Ulysses Grant nominated two new justices  to  the  Court,  Joseph  Bradley (1812-1892)  and William  Strong     (1808-1895),  who  would  overturn  that decision. Indeed, Bradley and Strong subsequently voted to reverse the Hepburn decision, in Knox v. Lee and Parker v. Davis, again on a one vote majority 5-4. The constitutionality of paper money was thus established thirteen years later in Juilliard v. Greenman. 

7The lawsuit that started the whole affair originated   when   one   Mrs.  Hepburn attempted to pay a debt due to one Henry Griswold on a promissory note, which was made five days PRIOR to the issuance of United States Legal Tender Notes central to this case. Griswold sued Hepburn in the Louisville Chancery Court on the note and refused Mrs. Hepburn’s tender of United States notes to satisfy his claim. She then tendered the notes into the chancery court, which declared her debt satisfied.

The  Kentucky  Appellate Court of  Errors reversed  the  lower  chancery  court’s judgment holding that the notes were not valid  for  payment,  and  Mrs.  Hepburn appealed to the United States Supreme Court. Most likely, there were powerful interests backing the lawsuit on each side because otherwise it would not pay to appeal such a case looking at the legal fees involved. The Supreme Court then affirmed the judgment of the Court of Errors. From a practical perspective, Mrs. Hepburn could have easily exchanged the notes elsewhere and provided the appropriate funds due.  Clearly,  nothing  of  the  sort  was  done because this issue was ripe to be decided.

The U.S. Supreme Court indeed acknowledged that the Federal Constitution of the United States is the highest law of the land and that the national government was powerless to do something that it was not authorized to do by the people. The Federal government holds the power to do things that are not expressly granted in the Constitution, so long as they are incidental to it. 

 US Constitution Article VI, Section 2:

8

Treaties made, or which shall be made, under the Authority of the United States, shall be the supreme Law of the Land; and the Judges in every State shall be bound thereby, any Thing in the Constitution or Laws of any State to the Contrary notwithstanding. This Constitution, and the Laws of the United States which shall be made in Pursuance thereof; and all 

9

 The Hepburn Court went on to explain how the United States Congress has the power to coin money. However, the Court held that the power to coin money was distinctly different from the power to make paper legal tender. Indeed, we can see plainly from Article I, Section 10 that the Constitution did not authorize paper money. Indeed, no paper money was ever issued by the United States until the Civil Way in 1861. That means that for the first 69 years, there was no government paper money. The first issue was that shown above in 1861. However, a demand note is simply a recipt. It does not purport to be money itself. That is where the formal declaration of 1862 declared paper money directly to be Legal Tender for all debts public and private.

US Constitution, Article I, Section 10

No State shall enter into any Treaty, Alliance, or Confederation; grant Letters of Marque and Reprisal; coin Money; emit Bills of Credit; make any Thing but gold and silver Coin a Tender in Payment of Debts; pass any Bill of Attainder, ex post facto Law, or Law impairing the Obligation of Contracts, or grant any Title of Nobility.

The Court discussed that the government holds the power to carry on war and since these demand notes or greenbacks were issued to finance the American Civil War, perhaps Congress could make these notes legal tender under that power if they were incidental. 10Nevertheless, the Court reasoned that making notes legal tender was not necessary to carry on war. Clearly, the reasoning is straight forward. There are no tricks or clever manipulations of words. Paper Currency existed both at the state and federal level. It is hard to reason that expressly stating that money should only be coin somehow leaves the window open for paper money when the Founding Fathers were well aware such currency existed. 

111

2012 Conferences

We will be holding three World Economic Conferences this year. These will be substantially different from the Philadelphia Conference. That was a combination of an Analytical Training Seminar and a World Economic Conference. Normally, each type of session is a two day event. Consequently, these two events had to be crammed into two days. Unfortunately, we could not accommodate everyone. We had to turn down 365 people. Traditionally, these events are limited to 100 attendees. Because of the overwhelming response, the room was full to capacity at 300+. That prohibited Mr. Armstrong from mingling with the crowd at the cocktail party and he was unable to see each and every person. These three upcoming conferences will be
smaller, just forecasting, and will be two day events instead of the single day WEC which was provided in Philadelphia. Seating will be $1500 per seat. Those who are interested in attending please send your email to reserve a seat to:

 Please Reserve your Seat Now

[email protected]

121

It is one thing to issue paper money that paid interest. This was a form of circulating bond. It was also distinctly different to issue a  demand note  that merely guaranteed that the Treasury had the coin on hand and would redeem the note at any time. However, it was an entirely different animal to then create a note and call it  legal tender  for it was now money no different than coin itself. As long as the paper paid interest or could be redeemed for coin, it was NOT money directly itself. 

131

The Hepburn Court in 1869 also talked about how the Constitution prohibits the several states from impairing the obligations of contracts or coining its own money. It court concluded that although there is no such express prohibition against the federal government, it would violate the spirit of the Constitution for the federal government to assume it could violate those very same principles.

The Latin maxim expressio unius est exclusio alterius is a doctrine of statutory construction that is supposed to inform a judge how to interpret a statute. It states that the mention of one thing in a statute impliedly excludes another thing. Generally, the expression of one or more items of a class when specified implies that those NOT identified are to be excluded.   Likewise, the inclusio unius est exclusio alterius doctrine states that when a law expressly describes a particular situation in which something should apply, an inference must be drawn that what is not included by specific reference was intended to be omitted or excluded. Since the Constitution expressly states that no state shall  make any Thing but gold and silver Coin a Tender in Payment of Debts  it would be impossible to be carried out if the federal government were excluded.

The Hepburn Court explained (75 US at 608):

Contracts for the payment of money, made before the act of 1862, had reference to coined money, and could not be discharged, unless by consent, otherwise than by tender of the sum due in coin. Every such contract, therefore, was in legal import a contract for the payment of coin.

There is a well known law of currency that notes or promises to pay, unless made conveniently and promptly convertible into coin at the will of the holder, can never, except under unusual and abnormal conditions, be at par in circulation with coin. It is an equally well known law that depreciation of notes must increase with the increase of the quantity put in circulation and the diminution of confidence in the ability or disposition to redeem. Their appreciation follows the reversal of these conditions. No act making them a legal tender can change materially the operation of these laws. Their force has been strikingly exemplified in the history of the United States notes. Beginning with a very slight depreciation when first issued, in March, 1862, they sank in July, 1864, to the rate of two dollars and eighty-five cents for a dollar in gold, and then rose until recently a dollar and twenty cents in paper became equal to a gold dollar.

Admitting, then, that prior contracts are within the intention of the act, and assuming that the act is warranted by the Constitution, it follows that the holder of a promissory note, made before the act, for a thousand dollars, payable, as we have just seen, according to the law and according to the intent of the parties, in coin, was required, when depreciation reached its lowest point, to accept in payment a thousand note dollars, although with the thousand coin dollars, due under the contract, he could have purchased on that day two thousand eight hundred and fifty such dollars.

Now it certainly needs no argument to prove that an act compelling acceptance in satisfaction of any other than stipulated payment alters arbitrarily the terms of the contract and impairs its obligation, and that the extent of impairment is in the proportion of the inequality of the payment accepted under the constraint of the law to the payment due under the contract. Nor does it need argument to prove that the practical operation of such an act is contrary to justice and equity. It follows that no construction which attributes such practical operation to an act of Congress is to be favored, or indeed to be admitted, if any other can be reconciled with the manifest intent of the legislature.

What, then, is that manifest intent? Are we at liberty, upon a fair and reasonable construction of the act, to say that Congress meant that the word “debts” used in the act should not include debts contracted prior to its passage?

We can see what the law was and how the Supreme Court should have ruled. Since compelling somebody to accept something other than what was contracted for was a taking of property, the Court found that making notes legal tender was a taking without just compensation and without due process of the law.

But the Constitution is the fundamental law of the United States. By it the people have created a government,
defined its powers, prescribed their limits, distributed them among the different departments, and directed in
general the manner of their exercise. No department of the government has any other powers than those thus
delegated to it by the people. All the legislative power granted by the Constitution belongs to Congress, but it has
no legislative power which is not thus granted. And the same observation is equally true in its application to the
executive and judicial powers granted respectively to the President and the courts. All these powers differ in kind,
but not in source or in limitation. They all arise from the Constitution, and are limited by its terms.

It is the function of the judiciary to interpret and apply the law to cases between parties as they arise for judgment.
It can only declare what the law is and enforce, by proper process, the law thus declared. But in ascertaining the
respective rights of parties, it frequently becomes necessary to consult the Constitution. For there can be no law
inconsistent with the fundamental law. No enactment not in pursuance of the authority conferred by it can create
obligations or confer rights. For such is the express declaration of the Constitution itself in these words:

“The Constitution, and the laws of the United States which shall be made in pursuance thereof, and all treaties
made, or which shall be made under the authority of the United States, shall be the supreme law of the land, and
the judges of every state shall be bound thereby, anything in the constitution or laws of any state to the contrary
notwithstanding.”

If it be otherwise, the Constitution is not the supreme law; it is neither necessary or useful, in any case, to inquire whether or not any act of Congress was passed in pursuance of it, and the oath which every member of this Court is required to take that he Not every act of Congress, then, is to be regarded as the supreme law of the land; nor is it by every act of Congress that the judges are bound. This character and this force belong only to such acts as are “made in pursuance of the Constitution.”

When, therefore, a case arises for judicial determination, and the decision depends on the alleged inconsistency of a

Page 75 U. S. 612 legislative provision with the fundamental law, it is the plain duty of the court to compare the act with Constitution, and if the former cannot, upon a fair construction, be reconciled with the latter, to give effect to the Constitution rather than the statute. This seems so plain that it is impossible to make it plainer by “will administer justice without respect to persons, and do equal right to the poor and the rich, and faithfully perform the duties incumbent upon him to the best of his ability and understanding, agreeably to the Constitution and laws of the United States,” becomes an idle and unmeaning form.

The dissent argued that the government was threatened by the war and making the notes legal tender provided the government with the necessary supplies to continue to fight the war. Therefore, the dissent generally rested its hat on the claim that making notes legal tender was legitimate as it was incidental to the power to carry on war. Of course that argument would not stand today in times of peace.

 

Page 75 U. S. 613

It becomes our duty, therefore, to determine whether the Act of February 25, 1862, so far as it makes United States notes a legal tender in payment of debts contracted prior to its passage, is constitutional and valid or otherwise. Under a deep sense of our obligation to perform this duty to the best of our ability and understanding, we shall proceed to dispose of the case presented by the record.

It is denied, indeed, by eminent writers, that the quality of legal tender adds anything at all to the credit or usefulness of government notes. They insist, on the contrary, that it impairs both. However this may be, it must be remembered that it is as a means to an end to be attained by the action of the government that the implied

Page 75 U. S. 621

power of making notes a legal tender in all payments is claimed under the Constitution. Now how far is the government helped by this means? Certainly it cannot obtain new supplies or services at a cheaper rate, for no one will take the notes for more than they are worth at the time of the new contract. The price will rise in the ratio of the depreciation, and this is all that could happen if the notes were not made a legal tender. But it may be said that the depreciation will be less to him who takes them from the government if the government will pledge to him its power to compel his creditors to receive them at par in payments. This is, as we have seen, by no means certain. If the quantity issued be excessive and redemption uncertain and remote, great depreciation will take place; if, on the other hand, the quantity is only adequate to the demands of business and confidence in early redemption is strong, the notes will circulate freely whether made a legal tender or not.

But if it be admitted that some increase of availability is derived from making the notes a legal tender under new contracts, it by no means follows that any appreciable advantage is gained by compelling creditors to receive them in satisfaction of preexisting debts. And there is abundant evidence that whatever benefit is possible from that compulsion to some individuals or to the government is far more than outweighed by the losses of property, the derangement of business, the fluctuations of currency and values, and the increase of prices to the people and the government, and the long train of evils which flow from the use of irredeemable paper money. It is true that these evils are not to be attributed altogether to making it a legal tender. But this increases these evils. It certainly widens their extent and protracts their continuance.

We are unable to persuade ourselves that an expedient of this sort is an appropriate and plainly adapted means for
the execution of the power to declare and carry on war. If it adds nothing to the utility of the notes, it cannot be
upheld as a means to the end in furtherance of which the notes are issued. Nor can it, in our judgment, be upheld as
such if,

Page 75 U. S. 622

while facilitating in some degree the circulation of the notes, it debases and injures the currency in its proper use to a
much greater degree. And these considerations seem to us equally applicable to the powers to regulate commerce and
to borrow money. Both powers necessarily involve the use of money by the people and by the government, but
neither, as we think, carries with it as an appropriate and plainly adapted means to its exercise, the power of making
circulating notes a legal tender in payment of preexisting debts. But there is another view, which seems to us decisive,
to whatever express power the supposed implied power in question may be referred. In the rule stated by Chief
Justice Marshall, the words appropriate, plainly adapted, really calculated, are qualified by the limitation that the
means must be not prohibited, but consistent with the letter and spirit of the Constitution. Nothing so prohibited or
inconsistent can be regarded as appropriate, or plainly adapted, or really calculated means to any end.

Let us inquire, then, first whether making bills of credit a legal tender, to the extent indicated, is consistent with the spirit of the Constitution.

Among the great cardinal principles of that instrument, no one is more conspicuous or more venerable than the
establishment of justice. And what was intended by the establishment of justice in the minds of the people who
ordained it is, happily, not a matter of disputation. It is not left to inference or conjecture, especially in its relations to
contracts.

When the Constitution was undergoing discussion in the Convention, the Congress of the Confederation was engaged in the consideration of the ordinance for the government of the territory northwest of the Ohio, the only territory subject at that time to its regulation and control. By this ordinance certain fundamental articles of compact were established between the original states and the people and states of the territory, for the purpose, to use its own language, “of extending the fundamental principles of civil and religious liberty, whereon these republics” (the states united under the Confederation), “their laws, and constitutions are erected.”

Page 75 U. S. 623

Among these fundamental principles was this:

“And in the just preservation of rights and property it is understood and declared that no law ought ever to be made or have force in the said territory that shall in any manner whatever interfere with or affect private contracts or engagements bonafide and without fraud previously formed.”

The same principle found more condensed expression in that most valuable provision of the Constitution of the United States, ever recognized as an efficient safeguard against injustice, that “no state shall pass any law impairing the obligation of contracts.”

It is true that this prohibition is not applied in terms to the government of the United States. Congress has express power to enact bankrupt laws, and we do not say that a law made in the execution of any other express power, which, incidentally only, impairs the obligation of a contract can be held to be unconstitutional for that reason.

But we think it clear that those who framed and those who adopted the Constitution intended that the spirit of this prohibition should pervade the entire body of legislation, and that the justice which the Constitution was ordained to establish was not thought by them to be compatible with legislation of an opposite tendency. In other words, we cannot doubt that a law not made in pursuance of an express power, which necessarily and in its direct operation impairs the obligation of contracts, is inconsistent with the spirit of the Constitution.

Another provision, found in the Fifth Amendment, must be considered in this connection. We refer to that which ordains that private property shall not be taken for public use without compensation. This provision is kindred in spirit to that which forbids legislation impairing the obligation of contracts, but unlike that, it is addressed directly and solely to the national government. It does not, in terms, prohibit legislation which appropriates the private property of one class of citizens to the use of another class; but if such property cannot be taken for the benefit of all without compensation, it is difficult to understand how it can be so

Page 75 U. S. 624

taken for the benefit of a part without violating the spirit of the prohibition.

But there is another provision in the same amendment which, in our judgment, cannot have its full and intended effect unless construed as a direct prohibition of the legislation which we have been considering. It is that which declares that “no person shall be deprived of life, liberty, or property, without due process of law.”

It is not doubted that all the provisions of this amendment operate directly in limitation and restraint of the legislative powers conferred by the Constitution. The only question is whether an act which compels all those who hold contracts for the payment of gold and silver money to accept in payment a currency of inferior value deprives such persons of property without due process of law.

It is quite clear that whatever may be the operation of such an act, due process of law makes no part of it. Does it deprive any person of property? A very large proportion of the property of civilized men exists in the form of contracts. These contracts almost invariably stipulate for the payment of money. And we have already seen that contracts in the United States, prior to the act under consideration, for the payment of money were contracts to pay the sums specified in gold and silver coin. And it is beyond doubt that the holders of these contracts were and are as fully entitled to the protection of this constitutional provision as the holders of any other description of property.

But it may be said that the holders of no description of property are protected by it from legislation which incidentally only impairs its value. And it may be urged in illustration that the holders of stock in a turnpike, a bridge, or a manufacturing corporation, or an insurance company, or a bank, cannot invoke its protection against legislation which, by authorizing similar works or corporations, reduces its price in the market. But all this does not appear to meet the real difficulty. In the cases mentioned, the injury is purely contingent and incidental. In the case we are considering, it is direct and inevitable.

Page 75 U. S. 625

If in the cases mentioned, the holders of the stock were required by law to convey it on demand to anyone who should think fit to offer half its value for it, the analogy would be more obvious. No one probably could be found to contend that an act enforcing the acceptance of fifty or seventy-five acres of land in satisfaction of a contract to convey a hundred would not come within the prohibition against arbitrary privation of property.

We confess ourselves unable to perceive any solid distinction between such an act and an act compelling all citizens to accept, in satisfaction of all contracts for money, half or three-quarters or any other proportion less than the whole of the value actually due, according to their terms. It is difficult to conceive what act would take private property without process of law if such an act would not.

We are obliged to conclude that an act making mere promises to pay dollars a legal tender in payment of debts previously contracted, is not a means appropriate, plainly adapted, really calculated to carry into effect any express power vested in Congress, that such an act is inconsistent with the spirit of the Constitution, and that it is prohibited by the Constitution.

It is not surprising that amid the tumult of the late civil war, and under the influence of apprehensions for the
safety of the Republic almost universal, different views, never before entertained by American statesmen or
jurists, were adopted by many. The time was not favorable to considerate reflection upon the constitutional
limits of legislative or executive authority. If power was assumed from patriotic motives, the assumption found
ready justification in patriotic hearts. Many who doubted yielded their doubts; many who did not doubt were
silent. Some who were strongly averse to making government notes a legal tender felt themselves constrained to acquiesce in the views of the advocates of the measure. Not a few who then insisted upon its necessity, oracquiesced in that view, have, since the return of peace and under the influence of the calmer time, reconsidered their conclusions,

Page 75 U. S. 626

and now concur in those which we have just announced. These conclusions seem to us to be fully sanctioned by the letter and spirit of the Constitution.

We are obliged, therefore, to hold that the defendant in error was not bound to receive from the plaintiffs the currency tendered to him in payment of their note, made before the passage of the Act of February 25, 1862. It follows that the judgment of the Court of Appeals of Kentucky must be affirmed.

It is proper to say that MR. JUSTICE GRIER, who was a member of the Court when this cause was decided in
conference, [Footnote 14] and when this opinion was directed to be read, [Footnote 15] stated his judgment to
be that the legal tender clause, properly construed, has no application to debts contracted prior to its enactment,
but that upon the construction given to the act by the other judges he concurred in the opinion that the clause,
so far as it makes United States notes a legal tender for such debts, is not warranted by the Constitution.

Judgment affirmed.

141

The very day of the Hepburn decision, President Grant appointed two new Justices whose job it was to legalize paper money. Bradley and Strong are thus those two men who are responsible for the entire existence of paper money as we know it today. The holding in the Hepburn case was explicitly overruled by Knox v. Lee and other Legal Tender Cases, 79 U.S. (Wall. 12) 457 (1871), in which Chief Justice Chase dissented. Yet what is fascinating is that the Supreme Court stated that Congress has no authority to debase the currency as they do with inflation.

For, 1st. Congress has no power given it to regulate the value of the money it borrows, but only of the money it coins, and of foreign coins. The analogy claimed would exist if the Constitution gave Congress power to borrow [79 U.S. 457, 468]  money and regulate the value thereof. But that it does not give.

And, 2d. Congress has no power to even materially debase the coin. A power to regulate is not a power to destroy.

Yet at the same time, how do men of reason get around what was previously held? Chief Justice Chase wrote in his dissenting opinion to Knox that they just refuse to comply with the plain language of the Constitution:

The fifth amendment provides that no person shall be deprived of life, liberty, or property without compensation or due process of law. The opinion of the former
minority says that the argument against the validity of the legal tender clause, founded on this constitutional provision, is ‘too vague for their perception.’

The Hard Money people say gold today should be money. What they fail to understand is that the Supreme Court has already ruled there need not be any such intrinsic value. This means you are going to have to seriously reform government and the first step will be imposing TERM LIMITS, eliminate anyone who has ever held a government job from being a judge and eliminate lifetime appointment, and prohibit the executive from bringing charges against anyone without a complaint signed by a private citizen. Here is what the Knox Court said:

Here we might stop; but we will notice briefly an argument presented in support of the position that the unit of money value must possess intrinsic value. The argument is derived from assimilating the constitutional provision respecting a standard of weights and measures to that conferring [79 U.S. 457, 553]  the power to coin money and regulate its value. It is said there can be no uniform standard of weights without weight, or of measure without length or space, and we are asked how anything can be made a uniform standard of value which has itself no value? This is a question foreign to the subject before us. The legal tender acts do not attempt to make paper a standard of value. We do not rest their validity upon the assertion that their emission is coinage, or any regulation of the value of money; nor do we assert that Congress may make anything which has no value money. What we do assert is, that Congress has power to enact that the government’s promises to pay money shall be, for the time being, equivalent in value to the representative of value determined by the coinage acts, or to multiples thereof. It is hardly correct to speak of a standard of value. The Constitution does not speak of it. It contemplates a standard for that which has gravity or extension; but value is an ideal thing. The coinage acts fix its unit as a dollar; but the gold or silver thing we call a dollar is, in no sense, a standard of a dollar. It is a representative of it. There might never have been a piece of money of the denomination of a dollar. There never was a pound sterling coined until 1815, if we except a few coins struck in the reign of Henry VIII, almost immediately debased, yet it has been the unit of British currency for many generations. It is, then, a mistake to regard the legal tender acts as either fixing a standard of value or regulating money values, or making that money which has no intrinsic value.

But, without extending our remarks further, it will be seen that we hold the acts of Congress constitutional as applied to contracts made either before or after their passage.

it is critical to understand that the Supreme Court in ruling that Congress has the power to create paper money and replace coin even though the Constitution did not provide such an express power, The Legal Tender Cases reversed Hepburn, beginning with Knox v. Lee. Thereafter, in Juilliard v. Greenman, 110 U.S. 421 (1884), the United States Supreme Court ruled that Congress had the right to issue notes to be legal tender for the payment of public and private debt. Legal-tender notes are Treasury notes or bank notes that, in the eyes of the law, must be accepted in the payment of debts. This raises the question about Congress authority to then delegate that power to the Federal Reserve.

Without question, the Legal Tender Act of 1862, 12 Stat. 345, enacted February 25, 1862, was unconstitutional. For Congress to issue legal tender paper currency, it had to have Amended the Constitution. By putting political hacks on the bench of courts, the Federal Government can eliminate the Constitution entirely with sophistry. Congress sought to issue paper money to finance the Civil War without raising taxes. The paper money depreciated in terms of gold and became the subject of controversy, particularly because debts contracted earlier could be paid in this cheaper currency.

Article I, Section 10 of the Federal Constitution explicitly forbids the states from issuing “bills of credit” or its own currency or making anything but gold and silver coin “legal tender”. It makes no sense to allow the Federal Government to do so and to debase the coinage and paper money once issued. The Tenth Amendment refers to reserved powers that only the states can exercise, as well as powers not delegated that continue to reside in the people. Article I, Section 8 of the Constitution specifically gives Congress power to “borrow money” and also power to “coin money” and “regulate the value” of both U.S. and foreign coins, and regulate interstate commerce. Nonetheless, the Constitution does not explicitly and unambiguously grant Congress the power to print paper money, to destroy the money through debasement (inflation), or make whatever it desires legal tender.

15

16

17

It is very clear that after the experience with paper money during the Colonial Periods, the Founding Fathers granted no such power to the Federal Government to issue paper money and did not do so until 1861. Even Vice President Thomas Jefferson wrote that the federal government has no power  of making paper money or anything else a legal tender,  Justice Stephen Johnson Field, dissenting in the Legal Tender Cases, argued that   Congress had no power to make paper money a legal tender. He contended that “the Constitution says that Congress shall have the power to make metallic coins a legal tender.”

Unfortunately, you really expect a federal judge to outlaw paper money is just unrealistic. Nonetheless, this illustrates the entire problem with courts that are stacked by politicians who are career employees. They will always, and without exception, rule in favor of government. You cannot obtain a real or fair individual determination in the United States today. Even the legal of taxation any the whole Marxist approach of taxing the rich at a greater percentage than everyone else. That defies the Equal Protection of the Law provision. 

18

Judge Robert Bork has in his hearings for appointment to the Supreme Court stated: “Scholarship suggests that the Framers intended to prohibit paper money. Any judge who thought today he would go back to the original intent really ought to be accompanied by a guardian rather than be sitting on a bench.”( Hearings Before Senate Committee on the Judiciary,100th Congress, 1st Session, Nomination of Robert H. Bork to be Associate Justice of the Supreme Court of the United States (1987). ). That intent was exemplified during the Constitutional Convention where, on August 16, 1787, in a vote of 9 to 2, the power to “emit bills of Credit” was stripped from the enumerated powers of Congress, listed in a draft version of the US Constitution. The original text of the August 6, 1787 read “The Legislature of the United States shall have the power … To borrow money, and emit bills on the credit of the United States”.

19Gouverneur Morris (1752 1816), moved to strike out “and emit bills on the credit of the U. States” on the basis that since the United States being given the authority to BORROW money, then armed with such credit it did not need the authority to issue bills or credit
(paper money).

The law is very clear as is the duty of judges. The Supreme Court stated this maxim:

First, always, is the question whether Congress has directly spoken to the precise question at issue. If the intent of Congress is clear, that is the end of the matter; for the court,

Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 842-843 (1984) 

20It was James Madison (1751-1836) who was instrumental in drafting Article III establishing the Judiciary who also stated bluntly that “the prohibition to bills of credit must give pleasure to every citizen,  in  proportion  to  his love of justice and his knowledge of the true springs of public prosperity.”

He further stated that the issuance of paper money has resulted in “an accumulation of guilt, which can be expiated no otherwise than by a voluntary sacrifice of the power  which  has  been  the instrument  of  it.” ( Federalist #44 (January 25, 1788).)

The recordings of the debates over the Constitution make is very clear that because of the hyperinflation experienced  during  the  Colonial period, the Founding Fathers were expressly prohibiting both DIRECT TAXATION as well as the DENIAL OF ANY RIGHT TO ISSUE PAPER MONEY as an alternative to borrowing. In the first instance, the Congress choose to follow Karl Marx and introduced the income tax moving for a Constitutional Amendment to grant that over-overruling and disregarding the wisdom of the Founding Fathers. In the case of the latter,  they  simply  replace  two  judges  on  the  Supreme  Court  who  altered  the  Constitution. Unfortunately, we have no recourse to deal with judges for they are outside of every democratic safeguard intended by the Revolution and will always remain the greatest threat to our liberty.

James Madison’s notes, from the Constitutional Convention in 1787, also include a footnote where he says that the Constitution would allow the federal government to make “use of public notes as far as they could be safe & proper“, but he makes clear that would not allow the federal government to use paper as currency or legal tender.   There is no confirmation that this was more than his understanding what took place at the Convention.

It is within this context that we must question what Congress has done by allocating authority of the money supply to the Federal Reserve. However, to whom does one complain? A judge? Good luck! 

Roman Coins 

211

 Authentic Roman Coins of Probus (276-282AD) 

        Extremely Fine fully Legible $100.00
Very Fine, Legible but high points worn $50.00 

221

Add $5 Shipping per order (NOT Per Coin) 

231

An Outlook For the Precious Metals  2012 into 2017 

$300 provided by email

241